Monday, October 3, 2011
A REGIME OF PRIMITIVE ACCUMULATION - Prabhat Patnaik
The recent exclusive focus on corruption has, perhaps inadvertently, diverted attention from the more basic phenomenon which underlies it, namely a process of “primitive accumulation of capital”. The definition of corruption according to the Prevention of Corruption Act of 1988, which is the starting point of all current discussion of it, refers to the receipt of “gratification” (not only monetary) by a public servant in excess of his or her legitimate remuneration. This however has an odd implication: if as a public servant I allow the appropriation of public property by a private entity, and receive no gratification for it, then it is not a case of corruption; but if I do receive some gratification for doing so, then it becomes a case of corruption. The loss to the public exchequer, and hence to the public, in either case is the same, but it becomes a case of corruption only when the public servant concerned receives some gratification for the act of permitting the private filching of public property. What is more, even where there is no direct gratification involved but the public servant receives indirect gratification in more subtle forms, it would still not be considered corruption.
For instance, any public servant who privatizes public property at throwaway prices, even when he or she receives no direct gratification for it, is invariably hailed for this act by the corporate media, by the Bretton Woods institutions, and by the global financial community, as being a “visionary”, a bold promoter of “entrepreneurship”, and a “liberal” thinker in tune with the modern times. This brings in its train a host of possible rewards: sundry “best Minister in Asia” (or similar) awards, lecture tours, World Bank assignments, offers of cushy corporate placements, various remunerative advisory roles, and post-retirement sinecure appointments. None of this however will be considered “corruption”. “Corruption” in short is confined exclusively to gratification received directly as quid pro quo; it does not cover the far more pervasive case of gratification received from the system as a whole. The current crusade against corruption therefore, by not looking at the system as a whole, misses the wood for the trees. Of course, one should not ignore the “trees”; and hence legislation against “corruption” even in this limited sense is important. But missing the wood is unpardonable; and the wood is what Marx had called “primitive accumulation of capital”.
Primitive accumulation refers to the appropriation of the property of petty producers, peasants and the people at large (through for instance encroaching on common property or cornering budgetary resources, or buying up State property t throwaway prices) by the capitalists or proto-capitalists. It is called primitive accumulation, as distinct from the normal process of accumulation under capitalism, because it entails not the reinvestment of the economic surplus produced under capitalism, but a process of filching the property of other non-capitalist segments: the peasants, the petty producers, the State and the community (“commons”). Now, corruption too entails a process of filching others’ property; so that corruption itself may constitute a form of primitive accumulation of capital, e.g. when a “public servant” demands a bribe from the common man. But big ticket “corruption”, of the sort that has surfaced of late, is not itself primitive accumulation; it constitutes rather a levy on an ongoing process of primitive accumulation.
Take the case of the illegal mining in Karnataka. The mine-owners illegally extracting the mineral resources and defrauding the exchequer are the ones who have been engaged in primitive accumulation of capital. The then Chief Minister of Karnataka who is alleged to have connived with the illegal mine-owners in exchange for “gratification” and hence engaged in an act of “corruption”, can be charged with appropriating a share of the booty, i.e. imposing a levy for himself on the proceeds of the mine-owners’ primitive accumulation of capital.
Likewise, the act of primitive accumulation in the 2-G spectrum case consisted in the handing over of resources that should have accrued to the public exchequer, and hence to the people, in a proper auction, to a bunch of capitalist on a “first-come-first-served” basis. When the Telecom Minister of the time allegedly got a “cut” from it, and hence engaged in an act of “corruption”, he was imposing a levy for himself (and his near and dear ones) from the proceeds of primitive accumulation. The expropriation of the people however came not from the act of “corruption” but from the act of primitive accumulation. Even if the Telecom Minister had not received a paisa of direct gratification, and yet distributed 2-G spectrum on a “first-come-first-served” basis, the public exchequer would have been equally defrauded, the filching of the people’s property (consisting of the difference between the price at which it was made available and the price that would have been obtained in a proper auction) would have been of exactly the same order of magnitude. “Corruption” only determined who the beneficiaries of this filching were and entailed the appropriation of a share in the proceeds of this filching.
This is a simple and obvious point; but a most disingenuous attempt is being made, both by Congress and BJP stalwarts, to obfuscate it. Since the mechanism of filching people’s property was the adoption of the “first-come-first-served” route, all political leaders who followed this route are culpable of abetting this filching, whether or not they received a paisa of direct gratification for doing so. This would make several Congress and BJP ministers who had either preceded Mr.Raja in the Telecom Ministry and advocated this route, or had concurred with his decision to follow this route within the UPA, open to the charge of attempting to make private entities defraud the public exchequer. To ward off this charge, a chorus is emerging from both camps that “the policy was right but its implementation (by Mr.Raja) was wrong”. Their focus, like that of many “anti-corruption crusaders”, is exclusively on “corruption”, and not on primitive accumulation, i.e. the defrauding of the public, for which they are responsible, and which provides the basic pool from which the proceeds of “corruption” are drawn.
Primitive accumulation entails a theft of the people’s property; it thrives therefore whenever a change in property regime is being attempted. The most brazen example of primitive accumulation in the modern era occurred at the time of the collapse of the Soviet Union, when the privatization of socialist property also witnessed a massive theft of socialist property, when billionaires sprang up overnight, and a whole new capitalist class was conjured out of thin air. Likewise in India the process of privatization which has been a part of the neo-liberal policy has been accompanied by, and created the conditions for, the massive process of primitive accumulation of capital, and the upsurge in corruption that thrives upon such accumulation, that we are witnessing today.
The introduction of “free markets” in lieu of the controls that characterized the earlier dirigiste regime, often derided as the “license-quota-permit raj”, was supposed to bring down “corruption”. This supposition was not far-fetched either: any rationing regime where prices are necessarily lower than what the “market will bear”, creates conditions for those who can afford to do so, to alter the distribution of the rationed goods in their own favour by paying a bribe. The freeing of markets and hence the removal of rationing, while it may be abhorrent because it excludes the poor from access to the rationed goods, should certainly bring down the necessity of such bribes and hence the scale of “corruption”. If the pursuit of neo-liberal policies, which were expected for this reason to bring down corruption, has on the contrary been accompanied by a steep escalation of corruption, to levels unparalleled in our recent history, the reason lies in the change in the property regime that has accompanied the freeing of markets, the thrust towards privatization which has given a boost to primitive accumulation of capital and hence to the “corruption” that it nourishes.
The escalation of “corruption” in the recent period is indicative of the fact that the proceeds of the primitive accumulation that has been unleashed by neo-liberalism are being shared pervasively by the political class (and the bureaucracy). It is not only the monopolists, the financial oligarchy, the land sharks, and the multinational corporations that are raking in the proceeds of primitive accumulation but also the government echelons at the highest level, which are recruited from the political class. But things are even worse. Significant segments of even those elements of the political class which are not “corrupt”, in the sense that they do not receive any direct gratification for conniving with primitive accumulation of capital, are nonetheless actively complicit in the process: they belong very much to the system that promotes primitive accumulation and benefit from the indirect systemic gratification mentioned earlier. We are in short institutionalizing a regime of primitive accumulation, with the bulk of the political class (barring a few honourable exceptions, notably the Left) being incorporated into this regime.
This has serious and disturbing implications for democracy. Democracy if it is to be authentic must presuppose the primacy of the political over the economic, so that the people do not become mere hapless victims of the immanent tendencies arising from the economic system but can collectively intervene through political praxis against such tendencies. (This incidentally is why authentic democracy is incompatible with capitalism, since the latter becomes dysfunctional if its immanent tendencies are frustrated through such popular democratic intervention, as the collapse of the post-war Keynesian-Welfarist experiment demonstrates). The primacy of the political in turn presupposes a separation of the political and economic realms, a non-incorporation of the former into the latter, so that it can act in an autonomous manner to right the wrongs inflicted upon the people by the spontaneity of the economic system. But if the political realm too is incorporated into the economic, if the separation of the two disappears within a regime of pervasive primitive accumulation of capital, then we have a serious enfeeblement of democracy.
Lenin, following the Austrian economist Rudolf Hilferding, had talked of a “personal union” between the magnates of finance and industry and the leading echelons of the State in the era of monopoly capital. This “personal union” is carried several steps further when it sustains a regime of primitive accumulation of capital. And such “personal union” amounts to sucking out the democratic content of the polity. The question is: how can we fight it?
The struggle against “corruption” is important, but insufficient, since it looks at corruption in isolation from primitive accumulation, and hence restricts the concept of “corruption” itself, by focusing only on direct gratification and ignoring systemic indirect gratification. What is more, even the struggle against “corruption” in this narrow sense will not be successful if it aims only to penalize the “corrupt”, and does nothing against the process of primitive accumulation. Even in China, where, notwithstanding the weight of public property, a process of primitive accumulation has made an appearance, of which illegal mining entailing frequent accidents and loss of lives, is an obvious manifestation, the corruption associated with such accumulation has not been eliminated despite capital punishment being meted out to the corrupt. Punitive action alone is never enough. For preventing corruption the process of primitive accumulation itself must be thwarted.
At least three steps, to start with, are necessary for this. The first is anti-corruption legislation. There is no reason why the serving Prime Minister or the higher judiciary should be exempt from such legislation, as is being suggested by the government, though of course the modalities of their inclusion (e.g. whether the judiciary should be covered under the Lok Pal or a separate judicial commission etc.) should be carefully worked out. The second step is a restriction on privatization of public property. The privatization of State property be resorted to, if at all, only in rare cases; and every single instance of privatization should be subjected to Parliamentary scrutiny in all its details. Any privatization without a “fair auction”, on the basis of “first-come-first-served” or other such “principles”, must be absolutely proscribed. Parliamentary scrutiny must enforce such proscription.
The third step is that the ownership and operation of all exhaustible resources must be with the State. State ownership alone, say of mineral resources, is not enough; if State-owned mines are handed over to private operators, then the scope for illegal mining increases. To prevent this, even the operation of mines must be a State responsibility, which was in fact India’s official policy not too long ago. Likewise, there must not only be social control over the use of scarce resources like land, but also the monopoly right of the State (through an appropriate State agency) to be the first buyer in any transaction involving a scarce resource, at a “fair price” fixed on some pre-specified principles. This would help in breaking land speculation which is a major source of corruption, and also act as a restraint on primitive accumulation via the snatching of land from the peasantry.
The demand for nationalization of land has a long lineage. George Bernard Shaw, influenced by Henry George, had championed it; and it was a major component of the Fabian programme. Friedrich Engels had been critical of the Fabians for not going beyond it, but nationalization of some portion of land must remain an essential component of any agenda for progressive social change. For restraining primitive accumulation however even this may not be necessary. State regulation of land use and State control over land transactions may be sufficient for it, and these can be enforced inter alia through the State having the first right of purchase.
The question may be asked: if State personnel themselves are complicit in the regime of primitive accumulation, then how can such measures be enforced through the instrumentality of the State machinery? In particular the advocacy of State control and regulation, which makes the same political class that is steeped in corruption responsible for combating it, may appear odd. But we are talking here about a package of measures which also includes legislation against corruption. State control in short is being suggested here together with control over corrupt practices by State personnel.
Ultimately however the only restraint on primitive accumulation and the corruption it spawns is intervention by the people. And this ipso facto also constitutes an assertion of democracy which primitive accumulation, by incorporating the political class within its circle of beneficiaries, necessarily undermines. A powerful popular resistance against primitive accumulation must be built, which alone can provide a bulwark for democracy. Fasts unto death by anti-corruption messiahs who substitute themselves for the people and obviate any need for popular intervention, no matter how well-intentioned they may be and no matter how successful their fasts may turn out to be in drafting wholesome legislation, can never succeed in thwarting either corruption or primitive accumulation.
(Courtesy : CUSAT_EBRF Seminar)
Subscribe to:
Post Comments (Atom)
Blog Archive
-
▼
2011
(75)
-
▼
October
(26)
- മുതലാളിത്തം സോഷ്യലിസത്തിനു് വഴിമാറിയേ തീരൂ.
- എന്തു് കൊണ്ടു് പൊതുമുതല് കൊള്ളയും ക്ഷേമ പദ്ധതികളു...
- ധനമൂലധനത്തിന്റെ അടങ്ങാത്ത ആര്ത്തി - പ്രൊഫ. കെ എന്...
- നവഉദാരവല്ക്കരണത്തിനെതിരെ ഉയരുന്ന പ്രക്ഷോഭം - കെ വ...
- വിടവാങ്ങല് വെല്ലുവിളിച്ചും കീഴടങ്ങിയും
- കേന്ദ്രസര്ക്കാരിന്റെ വഴിവിട്ട പോക്ക്
- System Error Capitalism Is Crashed! Install New Sy...
- സൂക്കോട്ടി പാര്ക്കും പിങ്ക് സ്ലിപ്പും - റെജി പി ജ...
- അറബ് വസന്തം ശിശിരമാക്കാന് യുഎസ് - പി ഗോവിന്ദപ്പിള്ള
- അമേരിക്കയിലെ "മൂലധനം തിരിച്ചു് പിടിക്കല്" സമരം
- വാള്സ്ട്രീറ്റ് പിടിച്ചെടുക്കലിന്റെ രാഷ്ട്രീയം - പ...
- കോര്പറേറ്റ് ഉടമകള്ക്ക് പ്രത്യേക നീതിയോ?
- കുത്തക കമ്പനികളുടെ തട്ടിപ്പുകളും അവ മൂടിവെക്കുന്നത...
- ഒരു പ്രാകൃത മൂലധന സഞ്ചയന വ്യവസ്ഥ - പ്രൊ. പ്രഭാത് പ...
- മുതലാളിത്തത്തിനു് ദശാമാറ്റത്തിന്റെ കാലം - പ്രൊ. പ്...
- For an Effective Lokpal: Government has to Respond...
- Stand of the Communist Party of India (Marxist) -...
- Finance Capital made Capitalism Redundant
- The Finance Capital and Plunder of Social assets
- അഴിമതി രഹിത ഇന്ത്യ – അണ്ണാ ഹസാരെ സംഘത്തിന്റെ സമരം ...
- CORRUPTION: CHALLENGE TO INDAN DEMOCRACY - K.N.PAN...
- Corruption and Development - Anupama Jha, Executiv...
- Corporate frauds and role of media in the cover up...
- THE RAPE OF BELLARY (KARNATAKA)
- A REGIME OF PRIMITIVE ACCUMULATION - Prabhat Patnaik
- A CLIMACTERIC FOR CAPITALISM - Prabhat Patnaik
-
▼
October
(26)
No comments:
Post a Comment